This paper shows that the most efficient way for China to fulfill its committed import purchases from the United States under the Phase One trade agreement is to mimic the effect of an import subsidy. The effective subsidies would divert China’s agricultural imports from other countries. We find that this trade diversion is especially strong for Australia and Canada, followed by Brazil, Indonesia, Malaysia, Thailand, and Vietnam.
In December 2019, the United States and China reached a Phase One agreement to end the trade war. Under this agreement, China committed to purchase $200 billion more imports from the United States in 2020 and 2021, covering products in the manufacturing, agricultural, energy, and services sectors (Bown 2020). While the coronavirus pandemic in 2020 may render this agreement moot or at least delay its implementation, it is still worth asking whether it can ever be achieved. For agricultural goods, the agreement was that China would purchase $12.5 billion more imports from the United States in 2020 and $19.5 billion more imports in 2021 than it had in 2017.
China is among the world’s largest importers of agricultural products despite its large overall trade surplus with the rest of the world. Since joining the WTO in 2001, its agricultural imports increased by more than 12 times between 1997 and 2015 (Figure 1). In 2017, China imported $132 billion of agricultural commodities from the rest of the world, of which $24.1 billion was sourced from the United States. As a result, the Phase One agreement would create an import target of $36.6 billion in 2020 and $43.6 billion in 2021, as shown by the horizontal lines in Figure 1. Since these targets exceed the highest prior values of Chinese agricultural imports from the United States, how can they be achieved?
Figure 1: China’s Agricultural Imports ($ billion) from the United States and the Rest of the World (ROW), 1997–2019
Notes: Data are obtained from China Customs Trade Data, and USDA for 2018 and 2019.
Methodology
To address these questions, Feenstra and Hong (2020) estimate a non-homothetic demand system for agricultural imports into China. We adopt a framework developed by Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal (2016) that combines an almost ideal demand system (AIDS) defined over products and exporting countries with a gravity equation in trade to identify the demand from each importer for the products from each exporter. The data used to estimate the AIDS-gravity equation consist of imports by 30 Chinese provinces for 58 agricultural commodities from 78 major trading partners, over 1997–2017. We are able to distinguish the elasticity of demand by commodity and country of origin with respect to price and income. Based on these key estimated parameters, we forecast China’s future import demand for US agricultural products based on our assumptions about rising spending on imports. Then we ask how China can achieve the 2020 and 2021 import targets.
The solution is to mimic the effect of an import subsidy on US imports
Effective subsidy increases Chinese imports from the United States, but diverts from other countries
The effective subsidy substantially boosts China’s purchases from the United States. Under the zero-growth scenario, where China’s import demand for each agricultural product is the same as in 2017, the subsidies would lead to increases in US imports of $12.5 and $19.5 billion in 2020 and 2021, respectively, or percentage increases of 51.9% and 80.7% (Table 1). However, increased imports from the United States would result in shifting trade away from the rest of the world by the same amount as a whole, with the diversion of imports being spread across other countries.Among the top ten suppliers after the United States (based on their exports to China in 2017), we find that this trade diversion is especially strong for Australia and Canada, followed by Brazil, Indonesia, Malaysia, Thailand, and Vietnam, and then Argentina, France, Germany, Netherlands, and New Zealand (Figure 2). Australia suffers the largest dollar drop in exports to China of all countries. Its exports to China will fall by $1 billion (or (10.8%) from a baseline of $9.18 billion in 2020, and fall by $1.67 billion (or 18.1%) in 2021. Brazil, the top supplier after the United States, would sell $0.6 billion less to China under a 42% subsidy in 2020 and nearly $1 billion less to China under a 59% subsidy in 2021.
Figure 2: Impact of the Subsidies on Other Countries (US$ billions)
Under the Zero-Growth Scenario
Diversion occurs for three reasons
We show that diversion occurs for three reasons: (i) a conventional substitution effect within products, which depends on the number of competing countries selling each product in each province; (ii) an income effect that arises due to the effective subsidy, which can offset the substitution effect in part or in whole; (iii) a further substitution effect that can occur across products, particularly as some expenditure shares in the AIDS system reach zero so that there is a renormalization of all other demand shares.
Figure 3: Impact of the Subsidies on Coarse Grains (US$ millions)
Under the Zero-Growth Scenario
We find different results for soybeans, which are a luxury good with income elasticity greater than unity. In this case the income effect is so strong that China’s imports from some countries are complementary to those from the United States and therefore rise rather than fall with the Phase One targets. Since Brazil is a principal supplier of soybeans to China in addition to the United States, it experiences a modest impact from the effective subsidies.
The Trump administration has engaged in numerous trade policy actions with China. The Phase One agreement commits China to a “managed trade” approach by buying $200 billion of US goods and services during 2020 and 2021, over its baseline purchases in 2017. We show that the most efficient way for China to achieve these ambitious targets is to mimic the effect of an import subsidy on US products. The magnitude of these “effective” subsidies on the United States in order to fulfill the Phase One agreement are admittedly very high. It can be expected that the increased imports from the United States would result in the diversion of trade away from the ROW. The impact on different products also shows a rich pattern of trade diversion across source countries due to the Phase One targets. Such a maneuver would violate international trade norms of equal treatment to trading partners, and countries experiencing a fall in their exports to China due to the effective subsidy on the United States would be justified in lodging a complaint with the WTO.
Authors’ note: This research was supported by Cooperative Agreement 58-3000-7-0087 between the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s Economic Research Service and the University of California at Davis. The findings and conclusions in this article are those of the authors and should not be construed to represent any official USDA or US Government determination or policy, nor do they necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
(Robert Feenstra, Department of Economics, University of California, Davis; Chang Hong is an Economist in the Economic Research Service of the U.S. Department of Agriculture.)
References
Feenstra, Robert. and Chang Hong, 2020. “Agricultural Trade and Consumer Demand in China,” NBER Working Paper No. 27383. Available at: https://www.nber.org/papers/w27383
Bown, Chad, 2020. “Unappreciated Hazards of the US-China Phase One Deal,” Trade and Investment Policy Watch, Peterson Institute for International Economics, January 21. Available at: https://www.piie.com/blogs/trade-and-investment-policy-watch/unappreciated-hazards-us-china-phase-one-deal
Fajgelbaum, Pablo D. and Amit K. Khandelwal, 2016. “Measuring the Unequal Gains from Trade,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131 (3): 1113–1180.