China is on a path to capital account liberalization. If the renminbi is to become an international reserve currency (e.g. Prasad, 2016), as it has started to and one day will be, China must have an open capital account. But once the capital account is open, the economy will be exposed to gyrations of the global financial cycle (Rey, 2014). This column argues that international credit supply shocks have powerful effects on real and financial variables of the receiving countries, but not all economies are affected similarly, and those that have lower loan-to-value ratios (LTVs) and limits on foreign currency borrowing (FXLs) are less vulnerable. As China lowers controls on capital flows (e.g., Benigno et al., 2016) it should consider tightening domestic macro-prudential policy regulations (e.g., Cesa-Bianchi and Rebucci (2017) to avoid excessive volatility.
In a recent NBER working paper (authored by Ambrogio Cesa-Bianchi, Andrea Ferrero, and Alessandro Rebucci) on the origins and the transmission of shocks to the international supply of credit, we provide indirect evidence that limits on the loan-to-value ratio (LTV) and the share of foreign exchange liabilities (FXL) could be effective in taming the global financial cycle.
Figure 1 shows that countries with lower maximum LTV and FXL are significantly less sensitive to capital flow shocks. The figure plots the peak response of real private consumption, real house prices, and the real exchange rate vis-à-vis the US dollar to an international credit supply shock against the maximum LTV and the average FXL in a cross-section of 48 advanced and emerging economies (Panels A and B, respectively—correlation coefficient and t-statistics in parenthesis). In the scatter, the larger red dot is China.
Figure 1: Sensitivity to international credit supply shocks
Panel A. Peak impulse response and maximum loan to value ratio (LTV)
Panel B. Peak impulse response and average share of foreign currency liability (FXL)
This shock is identified with a change in the leverage of US broker-dealers in a small open economy VAR that also includes BIS cross-border credit and the current account balance as a share of GDP. The identification of the external shock rests on the assumption that country-specific shocks are idiosyncratic and cannot affect the leverage of the US broker-dealer sector. To ensure that domestic shocks common across many small open economies do not affect leverage of US broker-dealers, in robustness checks we consider specifications that also include world GDP. The country sample excludes the United States.
In the paper, we also develop a model of collateralized borrowing with international financial intermediation to underpin the identification and the transmission of the shock in the VAR model. In the theoretical model, when leverage increases, possibly because of changes in the regulation of global banks, financial innovation, or monetary policy changes in the United States, global financial intermediaries have more capital to deploy and extend more and cheaper loans internationally. But the sensitivity of individual countries to the increased international supply of credit depends on domestic conditions.
If the economy is financially constrained before the shock, as it is plausible to assume for many households and firms in China, or if the shock is large enough to push credit demand against foreign lenders’ borrowing limits (even if the borrower was unconstrained before the shock), house price inflation magnifies the initial impact of the international credit supply expansion by inflating the value of housing collateral; the higher the maximum LTV and the average FXL, the greater the impact.
A lower LTV limit in the domestic economy implies that domestic households are less leveraged. Thus, if the credit constraint is binding, a given increase in house prices will have a smaller impact on the economy’s borrowing capacity and hence housing and non-housing consumption.
Exchange rate changes affect the transmission of the shock through three channels in this model, both when the economy is financially constrained and when it is not. But not all channels work in the same direction. An appreciation always strengthens the purchasing power of a given quantity of domestic output, but reduces the domestic currency value of a given amount of loans contracted in foreign currency. In addition, when the domestic borrowing constraint binds, an appreciation will inflate the foreign currency value of the collateral and hence boosts the borrowing capacity in foreign currency. The net effect of these three channels is a quantitative and empirical matter.
The VAR results shows that in a large cross-section of countries, the identified international credit supply shock pushes up cross-border credit and consumption (Figure 2). The typical economy (as represented by the average response) also displays current account deterioration, real exchange rate appreciation, and a house price boom. House price increases in particular are hump-shaped and consistent with real yields declining over time in line with the predicted drop in borrowing costs and yields on risky assets.
Figure 2: Impulse response to a one-standard deviation shock to US broker-dealer leverage (International credit supply shock)
Notes: Average US broker-dealer leverage over the sample period about 20. Trimmed simple average of country specific impulse responses, excluding the United States. One and two standard deviation error bands based on dispersion of country estimates.
Importantly, the data also show that the identified shock explains a sizable portion of consumption variance in the typical small open economy, in the order of 15 percent of total variance (Figure 3). Both the impulse responses and the variance decomposition of consumption display significant heterogeneity across countries represented by the error bands around the mean estimate, which underpin the dispersion associated with LTV and FXL and reported in Figure 1.
Figure 3: Share of total consumption variance explained by the international credit supply shock at different time horizons (In percent)
Notes: Trimmed simple average of country specific impulse responses, excluding the United States. One and two standard deviation error bands based on dispersion of country estimates.
What does this evidence mean for China? Figure 1 shows that China (depicted with a larger red dot in the scatter plots), thus far, has been relatively insulated from the global financial cycle, here represented by our international credit supply shock. The response of consumption, house prices, and the exchange rate are indeed close to zero. This is despite a relatively high share of foreign currency debt and maximum LTV limits.
But of course there are other country characteristics that affect an economy’s vulnerability to capital flow gyrations. Figure 4 shows that countries with a higher level of capital controls—China having one of the highest levels—are less sensitive to capital flow shocks.
Figure 4: Sensitivity to international credit supply shocks
Panel A. Peak impulse response and average capital controls on inflows
This empirical evidence has important implications for China. Our results suggest that, if and when China opens its capital account as part of the renminbi internationalization process, it will likely experience increased volatility in response to international credit supply shocks. China, however, could tighten domestic macro-prudential regulation to manage its exposure to the global financial cycle. While LTV ratios and FXL shares are ultimately chosen by borrowers and lenders in the context of a given regulatory framework, our empirical evidence suggests that they are connected to consumption and asset price responses. As a result, by affecting the LTV and the FXL share, regulation might be able to influence market outcomes and thus stabilize the economy’s response to possibly inefficient capital flows shocks.
(Ambrogio Cesa-Bianchi, Macro Financial Analysis Division of the Bank of England; Andrea Ferrero, Department of Economics at the University of Oxford; Alessandro Rebucci, the Johns Hopkins University Carey Business School.)
References
Benigno, Gianluca; Chen, Huigang; Otrok, Christopher; Rebucci, Alessandro; and Young, Eric R., 2016. “Optimal capital controls and real exchange rate policies: A pecuniary externality perspective,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, 84(C), 147-165.
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304393216301064
Cesa-Bianchi, Ambrogio; Ferrero, Andrea; and Rebucci, Alessando, 2017. “International Credit Supply Shocks,” NBER Working Papers 23841.
http://www.nber.org/papers/w23841
Cesa-Bianchi, Ambrogio and Rebucci, Alessandro, 2017) “Does easing monetary policy increase financial instability?” Journal of Financial Stability, 30, 111-125.
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1572308917302620
Prasad, Eswar, 2016. “China’s efforts to expand the international use of the renminbi,” Report prepared for the U.S.-China Economic and Security Review Commission, Brookings Institution.
https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2016/07/RMBReportFinal.pdf.
Rey, Helene, 2014. “Dilemma not trilemma: the global cycle and monetary policy
Independence,” Proceedings - Economic Policy Symposium - Jackson Hole, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
https://www.kansascityfed.org/bPmQP/publicat/sympos/2013/2013Rey.pdf.